Political power-sharing, firm entry, and economic growth: Evidence from India

Article

Published 25.11.22
Photo credit:
Christian Senger

Politicians who share power impose checks and balances on each other, improving local governance and leading to better economic outcomes.

The distribution of political power affects the nature of economic institutions and subsequently, economic growth (Acemoglu et al. 2005). Political institutions are designed to provide incentives as well as impose constraints on key actors, thereby regulating the distribution of power in society. Political theorists have long debated the fundamental trade-off between the concentration of power among politicians and the necessity of checks and balances in understanding the optimal design of political institutions (Montesquieu 1748, Locke 1824). Political institutions such as the constitution, are often incomplete contracts, leaving room for abuse of power. Bringing together political actors with misaligned interests, yet requiring them to agree on policy, imposes checks and balances while guiding economic growth (Persson et al. 1997). One possible way to do so is to have multiple elected representatives govern a single jurisdiction.

Our paper (Dutta et al. 2022) examines this particular feature of the political-institutional design – multiple elected representatives or multiple politicians – and tests if increasing the number of politicians governing a jurisdiction affects its economic outcomes. While having multiple elected representatives might improve local economic outcomes by imposing checks and balances on each other, having multiple politicians might also induce agency costs, potentially deteriorating economic outcomes. An extensive literature (Bernheim and Whinston 1986, Dixit 1997, Dixit et al. 1997) highlights these common agency problems, resulting from having multiple principals, such as coordination failure, duplication of effort, and free-riding. 

Haphazard overlap of electoral and administrative jurisdictions

An ideal experiment to test the effect of multiple politicians on firm entry and subsequent economic growth would entail a quasi-random distribution of the number of politicians governing otherwise similar areas. India – the world’s largest democracy – provides such a setting. Following Gulzar and Pasquale (2017), our study uses the haphazard overlap of different administrative jurisdictions – administrative blocks and electoral jurisdictions (state assembly constituencies). Historically, administrative blocks have been drawn to equalise land revenue collection across the administrative units while electoral boundaries equalise populations across all electoral constituencies within a state. This differential objective provides a set-up where an administrative block is either wholly inside an assembly constituency (unsplit block) or partially split across multiple electoral constituencies (split blocks). 

Figure 1: Representative case of split and unsplit blocks.

Notes: The figure illustrates a case of adjacent split and unsplit blocks in our sample. The split block is the administrative block of Morshi, in the district of Amaravati, Maharashtra. This block is split between the two assembly constituencies of Morshi and Teosa. The neighbouring unsplit block is the administrative block of Warud, in the district of Amaravati, Maharashtra.

Figure 1 illustrates such an example. A block, whether wholly or partially inside an assembly constituency, comes under the jurisdiction of the political representative - a member of the State Legislative Assembly (MLA). As a result, blocks and, therefore block development officers (BDOs), are either under the jurisdiction of multiple politicians (split blocks) or a single politician (unsplit blocks). Figures 2a and 2b illustrate the overlap in administrative and electoral boundaries and the distribution of split and unsplit blocks for one of the Indian states – Karnataka. The haphazard overlap of constituency and block boundaries generates variation in the number of politicians governing a block.

Figure 2: Overlap of administrative and electoral boundaries

                       Figure 2a                                                 Figure 2b         

Notes: The figure presents the overlap of the administrative and electoral boundaries, as an example, from the state of Karnataka, and the formation of split and unsplit blocks. The boundaries of administrative units (blocks) are in red. The boundaries of political units (assembly constituencies) are in blue. Figure 2a shows the overlap of the electoral and administrative boundaries. Figure 2b presents a graphic depiction of split blocks in grey and unsplit blocks in white.

We estimate the causal effect of multiple politicians on the outcomes of interest using a regression discontinuity design. We compare outcomes of interest in villages located just inside a split block relative to villages on the other side of the boundary within an unsplit block, as illustrated in Figure 3. Close geographic proximity implies the villages close to the boundary are similar in terms of observables such as geography, history, law, access to public goods and facilities, and unobservables such as culture, institutions, and attitudes, among other features. This design ensures that villages in unsplit blocks are valid counterfactuals to villages situated inside the split block.

Figure 3: Illustration of empirical strategy

Notes: The figure illustrates our baseline estimation strategy. We estimate the causal effect of multiple politicians using a spatial regression discontinuity design, comparing outcomes in villages close to the boundary separating split blocks from unsplit blocks.

Multiple politicians and economic outcomes

We find that having multiple politicians improves the economic trajectory of a jurisdiction. Comparing villages on either side of the boundary separating split and unsplit blocks, we find that the number of new firms is 3% higher in villages just inside a split block relative to villages in unsplit blocks just outside the boundary. Similarly, being a village just inside a split block is associated with 7% higher night light intensity relative to villages in unsplit blocks just outside the boundary. Additionally, we find that villages just inside a split block have 5% higher employment, and reduced demand for unemployment benefits, which is reflected in the lower application rates to the national rural employment guarantee scheme (Mahatma Gandhi National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (MNREGA)). 

Figure 4: Regression discontinuity plots for firm entry (4a) and nightlights (4b)

                                  Figure 4a                                                                 Figure 4b

Notes: The figure presents Regression Discontinuity (RD) plots for our primary outcomes and the mean value of each outcome variable at different bins along the running variable (distance to the boundary), as well as with a local linear trend estimated separately, along with 95% confidence intervals, on each side of the discontinuity. The unit of observation is a village. The red dots indicate villages in the split blocks, and the blue dots indicate villages in the unsplit blocks. Figure 4a presents the RD plots for firm entry. Figure 4b presents the RD plots for nightlights.

We also corroborate the findings by exploiting an episode of delimitation of electoral constituencies, which changed the spatial composition of split and unsplit blocks. Certain blocks retained their status, while others switched from being split to unsplit (or vice versa). We find an increase in firm entry when blocks get converted from unsplit to split, and lower firm entry when a block switches from split to unsplit.

Checks and balances

We investigate if potential checks and balances drive multiple politicians to provide a better economic environment that facilitates firm entry. Checks and balances between multiple politicians will be higher if the interests of the politicians are misaligned (Persson et al. 1997). We explore two dimensions on which political interests might vary – partisanship and identity. Exploiting the differences in political parties and the caste of politicians in split blocks, we find greater firm entry in blocks split across politicians who are non-aligned in either of these dimensions.

We further investigate checks and balances by examining the private returns that politicians make through the power of their public office. Fisman et al. (2014) show that a relatively high rate of growth in assets of the winning politician (winner’s premium) reflects rent-seeking by the winner. Constituencies with a higher proportion of split blocks should impose stronger checks and balances on their political representatives. We find that private returns to public office are lower in constituencies with a high share of split blocks, suggestive of stronger checks and balances. 

Increased checks and balances due to having multiple politicians seems to reduce rent-seeking and therefore, might improve the ease of doing business. We explore several dimensions of cross-sectional heterogeneity in industry and firm characteristics to evaluate the potential pathways underlying business formation in blocks with multiple politicians.

We find a higher entry of firms in regulated industries, suggestive of a reduction in regulatory bottlenecks in blocks with multiple politicians. We provide direct evidence showing that the projects announced in split blocks take less time to receive regulatory approvals, and also experience lower cost overruns to build projects. We find a lower entry of firms in industries susceptible to cronyism. This is consistent with the idea that quid pro quo between crony firms and politicians can crowd out the entry of other firms (Zingales 2017). Finally, we observe greater entry of small firms. This is suggestive of the ease of doing business improving, since smaller firms are more likely to be adversely affected by political rent-seeking (Svensson 2003, Colonnelli and Prem 2022).

Conclusion

Those designing political institutions have long grappled with how to appropriately allocate political power. We find that having multiple politicians govern a single jurisdiction improves the local economy, as evidenced by greater firm entry and economic growth, and this effect seems to be stronger when their interests are more divergent to start with. Increased checks and balances, as a result of having multiple politicians, boost the local economy by improving state efficiency and reducing regulatory costs and cronyism. Our findings add to the current understanding of horizontal decentralisation, a common feature across several decentralised governance systems.

References

Acemoglu, D, S Johnson and J A Robinson (2005), “Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth”, Handbook of Economic Growth 1: 385-472.

Bernheim, B D and M D Whinston (1986), “Common agency”, Econometrica 54(4): 923-942.

Colonnelli, E, and M Prem (2022), “Corruption and firms”, The Review of Economic Studies 89(2): 695-732.

de Secondat Montesquieu, C. (1748). The spirit of laws

Dixit, A (1997), “Power of incentives in private versus public organizations”, American Economic Review 87(2): 378–382.

Dixit, A, G M Grossman, and E Helpman (1997), “Common agency and coordination: General theory and application to government policy making”, Journal of Political Economy 105(4): 752–769.

Dutta, H, P Ghosh, A Sarkar, and N Vats (2022), “Political Power-Sharing, Firm Entry, and Economic Growth: Evidence from Multiple Elected Representatives”, Working Paper.

Fisman, R, F Schulz, and V Vig (2014), “The private returns to public office”, Journal of Political Economy 122(4): 806-862.

Gulzar, S and B J Pasquale (2017), “Politicians, bureaucrats, and development: Evidence from India”, American Political Science Review 111(1): 162-183.

Locke, J. (1824). Two Treatises of Government.

Persson, T, G Roland, and G Tabellini (1997), “Separation of powers and political accountability”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(4): 1163–1202.

Svensson, J (2003), “Who must pay bribes and how much? Evidence from a cross-section of firms”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(1): 207–230.

Zingales, L (2017), “Towards a political theory of the firm”, Journal of Economic Perspectives 31(3): 113–30.