Terrorism financing, recruitment, and attacks

Article

Published 17.08.20

Financial counterterrorism is under attack for being costly and ineffective, but a new study shows it can reduce terrorist attack casualties

A record number of terrorist attacks took place in the past decade all over the world (Start 2017). Amongst the factors responsible for this rise, a large consensus points towards extremist organisations improving their funding and recruitment activities (Feldstein 2008). The nature of these events stimulated academics and policymakers to study the organisational economics of terrorist groups (Berman 2003, 2011, Shapiro 2013). In doing so, a consensus emerged on the importance of financial counter-terrorism (Bueno de Mesquita 2005a, 2005b, 2007, 2013, Shapiro and Siegel 2007). 

In response to this, various initiatives were launched with the aim of curbing the financing of terrorist organisations. In 2001, the United States Treasury Department took the lead by empowering the Office of Foreign Assets Control (OFAC) and the Office of Terrorism and Financial Intelligence (TFI) to extend their financial counter-terrorism operations. Several other countries followed these initiatives and multinational organisations like the FATF and IMF, expanded their scope towards these issues. 

Limitations of financial counterterrorism

These programmes, however, have come under scrutiny by various commentators and major outlets, such as The Economist in 2005 and Foreign Affairs in 2017, for two key reasons: 

  1. The implementation of financial counterterrorism is costly: governments and financial institutions need to set up specific departments to go after terrorism financing, individuals see their bank accounts frozen without justification (and often for the wrong reasons), and trials are long and have uncertain outcomes. 
  2. It is unclear what the returns on financial counterterrorism are, with some commentators claiming that the benefits to such regulations may be small, or even zero. In fact, it is often argued that ‘following the money’ is insufficient to detect the activities of terrorist groups, as these organisations may be able to dissipate the money through their affiliates operating in various locations, and use the funding when and where it is most relevant.

Evidence on ‘following the money’: A natural experiment in Pakistan

Yet there is a limited amount of quantitative research that seeks to understand how the financing and recruitment of terrorist organisations work. As a result, it is unclear whether ‘following the money’ actually works. The lack of academic studies is due to the difficulty in observing the financing of terrorist groups and identifying relevant research designs to produce causal estimates of these channels. In a new PEDL working paper, I offer a quantitative investigation into the relationship between terrorism financing, recruitment, and attacks (Limodio 2020). This research validates the hypothesis that ‘following the money’ does allow authorities to uncover the activities of terrorist organisations and that changes in terrorism financing generate large effects on terrorist attacks and casualties. These effects are particularly intense when terrorist groups are successful in their recruitment.

The key contribution of this research is the study of a specific natural experiment in Pakistan, which offers exogenous variation in the amount, timing, and location of terrorism financing across more than 1,500 Pakistani cities and over 20 years. The results of this research show that the timing and location of terrorism financing correspond to the timing and the location of terrorist attacks. This result is consistent with terrorist organisations being unable to easily move financial resources over time and across locations.

Exogenous variation in funding available to terrorist organisations

I focus on a natural experiment inducing variation in a specific source of terrorism financing. Zakat is a charitable donation that Muslims offer to the poor during Ramadan and is meant to literally ‘purify’ the income and wealth of an individual by assisting the poor and vulnerable. It is typically administered through charities that specialise in offering these services during Ramadan. This type of ‘targeted donation’ is ideal for studying this question, given that many charitable organisations involved in these payments are opaque and that some of them – in Pakistan and the United States for example – have been accused of financing terrorism. It is important to clarify that the vast majority of charities (both Sunni and non-Sunni) are not associated in any way with terrorist groups, and provide valuable goods and services to poor and vulnerable individuals. However, there is evidence that part of the Zakat funding does end up in the ‘wrong hands’ and is used to finance terrorist attacks, as a Pakistani minister reported in 2015. As a result, changes in Zakat donations alter the funding available to terrorist organisations and Pakistan offers a unique setting that generates unexpected changes in Zakat donations.

Specifically, the payment of the Zakat takes place through voluntary contributions going through charities and a mandatory government scheme, which is exclusive to Pakistan. This mandatory scheme obliges a certain segment of the population to give their donations to the government rather than charities, through a banking regulation that imposes a 2.5% levy on bank deposits above a specific threshold on the first day of Ramadan. 

Two unique elements of a mandatory government scheme

Two institutional characteristics of this government scheme create unexpected changes in individual charitable donations, which affect the financing of terrorist groups and their attacks:

  • The first unique element is the definition of the threshold to pay the Zakat to the government in Pakistan. The threshold is defined as the monetary value of 600 grams of silver. Two days before the beginning of Ramadan, the Central Bank and Ministry of Religious Affairs check the price of silver, multiply it by 600 grams and announce the threshold. As a result, , the threshold to pay the Zakat levy to the government increases in years when silver prices are high, resulting in fewer people paying the government and more being paid to private charities.
  • The second unique element has to do with the fact that this rule only applies to individuals belonging to the main religious confession in Pakistan, Sunni Islam, with other religious groups being exempted from the deposit levy. As a result, Sunni individuals donate more to charities during Ramadan when the price of silver is high and they are not subject to the levy. Therefore, as silver prices imply higher donations, there is a higher probability that larger amounts reach terrorist organisations and fund attacks. Consistent with this argument, the empirical analysis shows that cities with a Sunni majority population suffer from more terrorist attacks during Ramadan, but only in the presence of high charitable donations driven by high silver prices.

Effect of terrorism financing is stronger in periods of intense terrorist recruitment

In the last part of the paper, I exploit an innovative measure of recruitment that combines data from Jihadist forums operating in the dark web, the work of two judges, and machine learning. I analyse data from Reddit-like forums operating in the dark web that have a clear Jihadi-friendly aim and are used by individuals to exchange messages and organise events. After sharing a random set of this data with judges who in turn evaluated whether such messages contain the intent to recruit, I applied a standard machine learning algorithm to the remaining millions of messages. This allowed me to gauge the messages that were aimed at recruiting individuals. Combining this measure with the Zakat experiment, I find that the positive effect of terrorism financing on attacks is stronger in periods of intense terrorist recruitment. 

Overall, these results suggest that financial counterterrorism can reduce terrorist attacks and casualties by ‘following the money’. This effect is particularly strong in periods of intense recruitment and radicalisation.

Editors’ note: A previous version of this column appeared on ProMarket and is based on this PEDL project.

References

Berman, E (2003), “Hamas, Taliban and the Jewish underground, an economist's view of radical religious militias”, NBER Working Paper 10004.

Berman, E (2011), Radical, religious, and violent. The new economics of terrorism, MIT press.

Berman, E, J N Shapiro and J H and Felter (2011), “Can hearts and minds be bought? The economics of counterinsurgency in Iraq”, Journal of Political Economy, 119(4), 766-819.

Bueno de Mesquita, E (2005a), “Conciliation, counterterrorism, and patterns of terrorist violence”, International Organization, 59(1), 145-176.

Bueno de Mesquita, E (2005b), “The quality of terror”, American Journal of Political Science, 49(3), 515-530.

Bueno de Mesquita, E (2007), “Politics and the suboptimal provision of counterterror”, International Organization, 61(1), 9-36.

Bueno de Mesquita, E (2013), “Rebel tactics”, Journal of Political Economy, 121(2), 323-357.

Feldstein, M (2008), “Designing institutions to deal with terrorism in the united states”, American Economic Review, 98(2), 122-26.

Limodio, N (2020), "Terrorism Financing, Recruitment and Attack", PEDL Working Paper.

Shapiro, J N (2007), “Terrorist organizations vulnerabilities and inefficiencies”, Terrorism Financing and State Response 58.

Shapiro, J N (2013), The Terrorist's Dilemma. Managing violent covert organizations, Princeton University Press.

Shapiro, J N and D A Siegel (2007), “Underfunding in terrorist organizations”, International Studies Quarterly, 51(2), 405-429.

START (2017), "Global terrorism database, national consortium for the study of terrorism and responses to terrorism", University of Maryland.